Monday, January 6, 2014

From Darkness to Light: The Fall of England's Feudal Economy



        From the 11th century onward, feudalism had a stranglehold on the island kingdom of England. As the norm of the land for hundreds of years, it seemed there was no foreseeable end to it, until the middle of the 14th century. As the adage goes, things had to get worse to get better, and after a series of calamities, England faced the downfall of feudalism and a century of prosperity. This begs the question, however, of why the catastrophes helped? What was so terrible that it changed the very foundation of the government, or did the power really shift much at all? And what effect did these events have on the common man?

         Feudalism in England was officially introduced in 1066 with the Norman Conquest, though elements of it had been present in feudalism gained prominence in the 9th century. It was a harsh system, with a rigid class-based structure that allowed for little to no upward mobility. If one was born into serfdom, there was next to no opportunities to advance, being stuck in a state that was often considered worse than slavery. Lords, barons, or other nobility were the only major landholders, with life being entirely dependent on the success of the lord's manor. This way of life began to crumble, however, after the first few survivors of the Crusades returned. These warriors would regale their fellow townspeople with tales of far off lands and vast riches, and would eventually inspire trade with faraway territories. After the Crusades, Venice, Genoa, and other cities along the Mediterranean took a central role in trade, profiting from dealing in Oriental goods, the growing significance of banking and, after the fall of their chief competition – the Byzantine Empire – their newfound monopoly. (Felsch, 2013) This expansion of trade trickled its way up to northern Europe, and by the 15th century, had permeated the economy of England.

        The population of England had been falling since the 14th century, however, and many historians believe it continued to fall until 1450-70. (Muhlberger, 2003) A major part of this decline was due to something known as the Black Death, lasting roughly from 1347-1351, though remnants could be found well into the 1400's. This was not the only crisis, but was the one that was engrained in legend. However, with a declining population, basic foodstuffs – especially grain, normally the main source of income for farmers – were not in high demand anymore, and consequently drove prices, and ultimately the farmers' own rent, down to prices never before seen. (Knox, 2013) Manual labor, on the other hand, was at an all-time high in demand. Wages began to rise, but many local governments attempted to pass laws restricting them, though such legislation was ineffective. Prices and land both dropped in price during this rise in wages, allowing much of the peasantry to create what one might consider a precursor to the middle class, whose rights could be defended by the king's justice. If they were able to labor, they could eat rather well, thanks to the new, higher wages earned. (Muhlberger, 2003)

         However, this did not necessarily mean the decline of the landlords. When many serfs and servants became freed tenants, some nobles who were set in their ways attempted the aforementioned legislation. Others, however, were more skilled at adaptation, and decided to turn their efforts to the production of material exports like wool. By doing so, they entered into an industry that was required less labor, and was vastly more profitable, but required new techniques to be effective. Enter fenced enclosures, pastures, and pens, something that had only been seen in limited aspects until now. Barons, lords, and landowners would convert once-plowed pastures of newly vacant villages and manors were fenced in and allowed to grow, to be utilized for sheep runs. (Muhlberger, 2003) Prior to the mid-14th century, the majority of England's wool was sold to France, Italy, and the Netherlands, where it was converted into usable cloth in the larger, industrialized cities. As the century progressed, taxes on the export of raw wool – imposed to support England's war effort – encouraged English landlords to send their goods to the local manufacturing regions, helping it to grow rapidly. (Felsch, 2013)

           Unfortunately, it was this very adaptation that spelled the downfall of the rising middle class, as the economic boom was not to last. Serfs had enjoyed protection of tenure with their lord. When 15th century servants gained their personal freedom, that security was retracted, and suddenly, serfs who had been dependent on their lord for all of their sustenance were on their own virtually overnight. Most peasants merely had a lease on the land they occupied. Leases used a leasehold, not unlike modern lease agreements. The leaseholds would end at a set time, at which point the landlord could renew it, modify it, or take the land back outright. Because of this, the newly-freed leaseholders had no long-term security. As the fifteenth century progressed, leaseholders were not terribly insecure because property was once again copious. Landlords lost  what influence they had, but by the 16th century, a growing population again made available property scant. (Knox, 2013)(Muhlberger, 2003)

          Overall, the economics of 1400-1500 England was the equivalent of a medieval roller coaster. The local populace was thrown about like a ragdoll at times, but those who were able to adapt and overcome weathered the storm best, regardless of serf, free peasant, or nobleman. Echoes of capitalism were seen, with the constant rise and fall of supply and demand; and it was here, in the wake of the Black Death and uncertain economic times, the people got a taste of their collective power.

References
Felsch, M., Astor, E., & Southard, Ü. (2013). Diercke International Atlas - Trade and economy in the 15th century. Retrieved from http://www.diercke.com/kartenansicht.xtp?artId=978-3-14-100790-9&stichwort=slave&fs=1
Knox, S. (2013). European economy in the Age of the Reformation. Retrieved from http://europeanhistory.boisestate.edu/reformation/economics/overview.shtml
Muhlberger, S. (2003). ORB: The Online Reference Book for Medieval Studies. Retrieved from http://www.the-orb.net/textbooks/muhlberger/15c_economy.htmlc

No comments:

Post a Comment